Articoli
RURAL SETTLEMENTS IN AFRICA
The
author is an Italian architect and urban planner with extensive teaching and
research experience in Somalia, Mozambique and Algeria in the problems of
development and precarious settlements: slums, shantytowns, rural environments,
and at Environment and Development in the Third World. This article is based on
an extensive study by the author and
Mohamed Arkoun, in French, in Villages
Socialistes en Afrique, published by ENDA - Tiers Monde, nr. 76-82, Série
Etudes et Recherches, Dakar, Oct. 1982, and in Italian: L’Utopia del villaggio socialista, Terzo Mondo, Milano, 1983.
Agricultural development and nomadism Breaking the colonial chains New settlement and farming systems
Socio-political frame and development approach
A number of governments, and not only in the Third World, are concerned with the
establishment of new farming population nuclei. The examples are many: the
drying out of swamps, the agrarian reforms in the fifties, the Cassa del
Mezzogiorno in Italy, the settlement of groups of American Indians in Western
Canada or groups of nomads in the eastern part of the Soviet Union. But,
obviously, preconditions and problems differ in different parts of the world.
Socio-economic
differences are determined by whether the aim is to densify the population for
natural or historical reasons or to establish fixed settlement areas for a
nomadic society. Fixed settlement areas can be for the simple provision of
services gravitating about specific wells and commercial centres to forced
settlement.
It is clear that the difficulties involved in changing from a nomadic to a settled
existence ere enormous and that several generations must pass to overcome
thousand year old customs, rivalries and prejudices which divide the world of
nomads from that of those who “toil by the sweat of their brow and live
imprisoned in their individual boxes.”
In Africa, the most notable example
of conversion from nomadic life to settled cattle farming took place in Libya,
in the oasis of Kufrah. Special techniques involving a fossil water table made
it possible to introduce a system of fodder crop rotation by which cattle could
then be raised commercially and the oasis population doubled in size. It was
however a very costly operation, made possible only by Libya’s wealth and
motivated by the need for stability along the Jamahiriya’s frontiers. In other
Saharan countries, especially along the Sahel belt, the situation is much more
complex.
Since 1974, drought has affected the nomads in the Sahel region. The numerous relief
operations have resulted in the nomads settling down, either voluntarily and permanently or temporarily.
Such temporary settlements swelled the peripheral city populations.
Ouagadougou, Upper Volta, for instance, grew from nearly 130,000 to 350,000.
When
nomads become urbanised, a specific kind of society, a culture, is destroyed.
Furthermore, the cities, already suffering from pathological peripheral growth
for which there is no adequate development alternative in the hinterland, are
confronted with yet another series of practically insoluble problems. Such has
been the case in Somalia, whose capital town, Mogadishu, the only city in a
world of nomads, houses some 20 percent of the country’s population. Mogadishu
leads an existence apart, and its links with the rest of Somalia consist only
of kinship relations between its inhabitants and the nomads in the interior.
Somalia
also furnishes an example of development action with the best of intentions,
but whose effects have been the opposite of those planned. In the sixties,
United Nations aid was used to sink a number of new wells in pastoral areas, in
an effort to create centres of attraction and encouragement for the nomadic
tribes. The result was disastrous. Heads of families, encouraged by the ready
availability of water, dramatically increased their herds - their only
form of wealth - but no one used the water to irrigate grazing lands.
When the drought set in, disproportionate numbers of cattle invaded the areas
surrounding the wells and completely destroyed all grazing land within range of
each watering‑place. Once all pasture circles around the wells had been
completely denuded of grass, the cattle began to die off. It was a catastrophe,
not only for the life and economy of the nomads, but also ecologically. The
natural balance had been upset over vast stretches of land, which would turn
into desert unless measures were taken in time to re-establish the plant
habitat.
For nomads, unlike for people living in cities, the width of territory and a proper
separation between them and their neighbours in day-to-day life are
of crucial psychological importance. In spite of this known fact, no planning,
with respect to the forms of settlement, guided the action to settle Somali
nomads.
Furthermore, clearing the areas to be settled involved the destruction of thousands of acres
of virgin forest. Village plans involved mere repetition of uniform modular
units. Plots of 12 square meters were too small for any kind of permanent
settlement in a peasant context, let alone one involving nomads used to living
a free life in open spaces and to measuring land in terms of so many days’ or
weeks’ march.
Under
colonial regimes, agriculture was organised into large single-crop
plantations for which the local inhabitants supplied the wage labour. The
output from such plantations was directly integrated into the world trade
circuits, destined for the metropolises and a system of exchange that benefited
only the large monopolies and the colonial governments.
The
colonial induced plantation system destroyed the original agricultural
organisation which the Europeans had found when they invaded the African
continent, just as the large scale slave trade and the political relations it
established between the European powers and the African vassal rulers blocked
all independent development by the African societies and cultures which, before
the European conquest, had been pursuing a highly original and unique
historical development.
The
large trading companies appropriated the best lands for their own use. New
cities grew up along the African coast in places where crops were assembled on
rivers or in the interior, and became markets for black goods and labour. At
best, the workers lived in slums on the city outskirts, and their labour was
exploited in the white-owned mines and plantations.
Those
blacks who escaped the process found themselves confined to more and more
barren lands. Marginalized in their own country, their social life became
impoverished. Self-subsistence farming on poor lands provided no
opportunity to progress unless selling one’s labour in the urban markets could
be considered social advancement.
This
process of underdevelopment was perpetuated during the one century of actual
colonisation, which followed the Berlin Conference held in 1884-1885
which carved up all of Africa between the European powers. Chronic marginal
underdevelopment created an enormous reserve of manpower at low prices, a much
more convenient situation than the black slave trade.
Because of this development, in
some remote forests or deserts certain African peoples remained “unexpIored”
and never, or only fleetingly, encountered white people. In the interior of the
continent, away from colonial penetration, certain archaic customs considered
as a means of enlarging the family labour force survived, like the
"sale" of women and polygamy. In Mozambique, for instance, it is the
women who work the land while the men defend and organise the family group.
Great wealth enables men to “bargain” for a number of wives from other
families. Households consisting of ten or twelve wives are not infrequent, nor is
it unusual to encounter men who are "married" to a score of women or
more, forming a small family farming concern.
One of the main tasks that new countries confront working towards economic
independence is to introduce new settlements and new farming systems in their
country sides. The eradication of single-crop farming was at the centre
of all agricultural development policies in revolutionary China during the
fifties and sixties, and it became the leitmotiv of Cuba’s internationalist policy. Unfortunately, in Cuba it is proving a failure,
and the country is now once more turning increasing acreages into cane fields
and making sugar exports the main state budget item.
But
food self-sufficiency and alternative forms of rural organisation
continue to be topical issues, especially in African countries which aim at
development on the basis of socialist principles. Tanzania is still considered
to be Africa’s standard bearer when it comes to self-reliant development and‑relying
on one’s own resources.
The cornerstone of the development program in Tanzania is the ujamaa vijijini concept, which involves
transforming rural settlements into a system of socialist villages (ujamaa, the
term for Tanzanian socialism, is a Swahili word meaning "cooperation in a
family spirit"). Community development in Tanzania has a character all its
own. Physical regrouping of peasants and assisting them in such sectors as
education, health, water and energy supply do not automatically mean achieving
a socialist rural society. What is required is long term education in
cooperation and community life and effective demonstration of the advantages
offered by associated production.
Historically,
two opposing schools of thought have emerged on the subject of socialising
agriculture: the first favours exogenous
socialisation, which may be defined as the colonisation of the village
communities by the industrial society; and the second emphasises endogenous
socialisation, i.e. a free association of village communities designed to
strengthen their position in relation to the affluence and economic clout of
the cities and of industrial society. This second approach, the result of a
process of developing the villages, might be defined as the “villagization” of
development. Forced collectivisation of peasants has always proved
counterproductive. Persuasion is a much more time-consuming and difficult
task, but one that pays dividends, both in time and in space.
When
confronting the problems of rural development, and the frequently proposed
approaches of poor architecture and self-help housing, it is easy to fall
into the trap of extreme schematisations. For instance, some view the attempts
at self-help housing and dwellers’ “participation” as decadent bourgeois
remnants within the frame of a new architectural approach caught between the
love for folklore and nature and a fascination with “do it yourself”; or some
claim that it is a “non-architectural” approach, as the limitations
imposed by the need to rely on the villager’s own strength leave no room for
creativity. Others, of course, state that this approach calls upon the
authentic culture of the people and their collective efforts, and still others consider
it as mere propaganda by political regimes which, in actual fact, believe that
real development depends on other sectors.
Reality,
however, combines several factors, and more or less severe objective imitations
may help establish an analytical framework for the evaluation of the various
experiences in the development of new villages. This framework can reflect the
socio-political point of view, or the more specific constructed form or, even
better, that of an indicator which combines both, such as flexibility,
identification, self‑realisation, cost, etc.
In
general terms, the following observations confirm the validity of the
participation of the village dwellers in the development of their settlement:
·
Collective labour in self‑help housing
cannot be assessed in commercial terms or quantified as an economic factor of
the final cost but only as a factor of real cost ‑ social cost in the
true sense of the word.
·
Houses built on the basis of an initially poor
and standardised plan ‑ in certain cases with “no plan at all” ‑
turn out to be more flexible in practice.
·
Families, even the entire community, share a
strong feeling of possession vis‑à‑vis self‑help houses,
whereas anonymous "turnkey" homes built by a specialised workforce
are seen as a highly valued asset, objects which ordinary family efforts cannot
produce, which cannot even be obtained without a minimum of special maintenance
preparation.
·
Even an entire village ‑ homes and
community buildings ‑ built with the use of only community skills and
local materials, is perceived as an ordinary real life object without any
commercial value. The structures are flexible and can be changed around by
their occupants. “Precious” villages, on the other hand, built by alien
technicians and with alien technology, are seen as a privilege, a symbol of
social advancement and stabilisation. The buildings, however, despite the
impression of non-uniformity would, in fact, fail to evolve as a living
organism. Spatial arrangement and size Conclusions and recommendations EKISTICS, Athens, vol. 51, nr. 304, Jan.-Feb. 1984.
Obviously
the two alternatives are governed by very different political and social
concepts. It is important, however, to remember that, in any society, a house
that can be changed around by its occupants tends to lose its Il aura‑ of
value object, and that the classes which have recently and easily gained
ownership of their home or car or any other status symbol, such as civil
servants, are the only ones that treat them with an almost holy
reverence not found either higher up or lower down on the social scale.
The study of the way villages are distributed in space and their average size deepens our analysis.
The aldeias comunais in Mozambique are
structured into a dense network designed to cover the entire national
territory, with especially high densities in two provinces (Cabo Delgado in the
north, Gaza in the south). In 1978, there were around 1,500 aldeias comunais and the average
population was around 700 per village.
In
Tanzania, according to figures published in June 1980, there were 8,300 "development
villages", officially defined as ujamaa. In reality, the
authentic ujamaa villages number no more than about a dozen (even Butiama,
President Nyerere’s birthplace, does not merit the designation ujamaa). French
agronomist René Dumont made an official report on the villages, at the request
of the President, after a three-month preliminary survey. The Dumont
Report should be seen as constructive observations on a subject for which the
author confesses basic sympathy.
Other
critical observations are more political, e.g. lack of prior consultation with
the people on the choice of location, insufficient attention to. the peasants’
individuality, too rigid a structure of power delegation at the grass roots.
"Socialism - says Dumont - has been imposed from above ‑
from the President to the masses. The latter are not at all convinced. The
peasants prefer by far to till their own small vegetable plot than the
collective fields... Nor do the villagers hold real power at any levels. They
are not represented in the governing bodies of the Party, dominated by the
urban classes. The real problem in Tanzania is still one of peasant power.
In
the four countries under consideration in this paper, the total number of
people affected by agricultural restructuration represents 3.5 percent of Somalia’s
population, 10 percent of Mozambique’s and 87 percent of Tanzania’s population. The number of Algerian people living in "socialist villages of the
agrarian revolution" constitute less than 1% of the total population, and
they are distributed among some hundred villages, with an average of 1,400
inhabitants each. The average cost of an Algerian village, equivalent
to some US$ 2.7 million, would finance the establishment of 260 Mozambican aldeias comunais and at least ten
settlement centres of the kind introduced in Somalia in 1975.
Densities in
the Somali settlement and Algerian villages are similar; the typology of the
latter being that of Maghrebian (Northwest African) cities, i.e. square houses,
narrow lanes between blank walls, opening on to a central space. The
distributive pattern is the same as among Somali families and in general it
crops up again in African settlements where the open space is used for both
cooking food and other dayly activities.
From
this overview, it becomes clear that examination of, physical environmental
issues, as part of “agrarian revolution” experiences in Africa, involves: the
choice of general planning strategy concerning the physical environment for
nomads, a critical examination of the ideology of “self-help” and
“fragile” or precarious housing, and an elaboration on the meaning of a
socialist idea in the context of countries that base their socio-economic
advance on the development of agriculture or in which such development involves
a majority of the population over a long period of time.
In
the case of the nomads, we must ask ourselves, what reliable" instruments
and scientific concepts can be used to exercise a political choice for these
peoples: total or partial settlement, upgrading of livestock farming (nomadic
or attached to specific centres), large cattle raising associations or mixed
economy cooperatives or any other flexible solutions tailored to specific
situations? At the same time, we must ask ourselves what really constitutes
“development” for a society of nomads who, for centuries, have pursued their
own form of self-reliant existence, living in equilibrium with the
natural environment. Can one really speak of socialism in the sense of
liberating man and his labour, while offering, or even imposing, a settled
existence for people whose nomadic way of life means constant communion and
confrontation with the forces of nature?
It
must be taken into consideration that the natural environment itself is today
changing rapidly, subject to the pressures of the “developed” world, in much
the same way as a century or so ago the prairies of the American West were
overrun by settlers who destroyed the nomadic redskin tribes or condemned them
to live in Indian reserves.
We
do not intend here to engage in a general debate on development options for the
Third World, but should merely like to highlight an alternative trend emerging
in the field of physical environment planning and action. This trend does not
openly contradict the "international style" esthetical currents,
because the mode is completely different and the instruments and objectives in
no way comparable. Very often, the technical staff responsible for planning and
managing self-help action does not come from official architecture and
town planning circles: often, too, they do not use an architects graphic,
verbal or cultural tools.
“Fragile”
housing provides homes for an emerging majority of the world’s population, not
only in the Third World and in the “periphery”, but also at the very heart of
the industrial society. The process of rapid urbanisation and the inadequate
public response are creating more and more shantytowns. We are now becoming
convinced that, the present resource distribution system being what it is,
there is little prospect of replacing precarious with stable housing.
The
“marginal people” deserve special attention not only by providing social
security but also by planning a better physical environment. This means
examining the natural physical environment the way it is, not as a deviation
from the norm but as the norm, at least in some places, and working towards its
improvement and growth. In doing so, certain traditional premises underlying
architectural planning are bound to be discarded. The first to move in this
direction were Latin American countries; their regimes were forced into action
when their favelas mushroomed and the
danger of potential social revolt by the urban sub-proletariat became too great.
Rural
settlement, the subject we are concerned with here, is a different reality. One
of its principal features is a shortage of building materials, aggravated by
supply and transportation difficulties. Under these conditions, local materials
and unskilled labour become a near spontaneous solution, based on thousand‑year
old customs.
Governments
and public authorities make a qualitative leap forward when they accept the
situation and support assisted self-help housing schemes. The leap is of
considerable psychological importance since it implies abandoning a set of
preconceived prestige concepts. The option is building homes for everyone that
guarantee a minimum standard of hygiene, sanitation and other services, or
building model homes for the very few. The former solution demands much greater
commitment and creativity on the part of the public authorities and a new
mentality among civil servants.
But,
in addition to substantial savings and other advantages gained from people
being involved in managing their self-made environment, the
architectural planning aspect of “poor” urban planning must be considered. It
is not feasible to improve the life of peasants by intervening only in
quantitative terms, i.e. by merely providing more square meters of services and
better hygiene. Today’s newly built urban peripheries, poor imitations of
Western models, are examples of extreme desolation. In such unbelievably dreary
surroundings, the desire to stand out or to appear modern makes house-owners
spend money on visible decoration, while the organisation of space is in a high
state of disorder.
The
need for decent housing low prices must be accompanied by a determination not
to create an alienating physical environment, often the result of the principle
that the progress consists of imitating industrial society. Above all, it is
necessary to adopt the advantages inherent in or inspired by local techniques
and building materials. Architectural planning should be a continuous presence
and assistance as well as a means to meet the specific needs of each social
group and family nucleus and provide for their mutual relationship. The model
house concept would be radically changed, the model no longer representing a
sample to be repeated “x” number of times, but rather as a suggestion, a
contribution to the planner.
As for
maintenance and the alterations that may become necessary over a period of time
(due, for instance, to changes in the family make-up), the occupants must
be in fuli control of the physical aspects of their dwelling, to feel capable
of repairing and renovating it. It is a tradition among the Algerian peasants,
and indeed among fellahin (peasant people) in general,
to place beds in alcoves built into the wails of a room. In the homes of poor
peasants the birth of a child, the arrival of visiting relatives or the
marriage of an adult son bringing home his bride are problems solved simply by
building a new niche into a wali of the house. This procedure would obviously
be impossible if the house were designed according to Western standards and
built in reinforced concrete. Multiple occupation of houses built according to
foreign standards leacis to overcrowding and brings with it social tension
previously unknown, even in the poorest peasant homes.
The
best thing any government could do would be to give each family not a free
house but the means to build its own home, to decide and to participate in each
phase from design to implementation. In this way, the finished product would
truly be an expression of the personality and the needs of those who live in
it.
Coopting local crafts is another factor in the defence of the economy and the culture
against aggression from outside in the form of goods and ideologies which,
although they may appear at first sight to be attractive, soon create
unemployment and subordination to the international market. They then destroy
the social fabric without repiacing it and substantially undermine the quality
of life. Handicrafts as an activity are integrated within peasant society,
adapted to its rhythm of life and human relationships, implying the best
possible use of natural resources. Replacing crafts with industrially
manufactured goods has been one of the most destructive effects of the
commercial impact of colonialism, hitting the most vulnerable societies most
severely. Local communities simultaneously lost much of their independence which
gave way to an accelerated transfer of resources towards the centres of
production, both the colonial metropolises and the big cities.
In
the Islamic world and other African countries, craftsmen occupied an almost
sacred place in village society. Manual skills were a means of mediating in
man’s relationship with nature for the creation of useful objects. The long
years of apprenticeship and the serene working rhythm were a form of meditation
and represented the means whereby society modified and utilised its resources
with humility, maintaining the natural balance. The butcher is an example. His
role is to destroy animal life in order to procure food for human beings. His
place in Islamic society is nearly sacred and his activities controlled by a
complex ritual which divests the act of shedding blood of all its potentially
aggressive content. The craftsmen do not suffer from alienation and live in
perfect harmony with their methods, tools and the results of their labour.
The
flood of “modern” goods has created unemployment among craftsmen, who handed
down their skills from father to son and whose knowledge formed a part of the
heritage of the entire community. Instead of controlling and transcending the
self‑subsistence economy, the community has now exchanged it for an
economy of dependency.
In
the new cooperative village structures, coopting the work of craftsmen is one
of the fundamental economic and cultural tools for emancipation. In Mozambique,
entire “craft villages” exist; in Somalia, the settled nomads are learning the
manual skills required to produce and repair the tools of their new work. Other
activities, such as wood carving and weaving, are excellent instruments of
social education. Obviously, the skills of the master bricklayer or, more generally,
the house builder are of great value, for they are the custodians of the secret
of the most economic and well-adapted building techniques using local
materials.
By contrast, the architect involved in rural housing programs tends to live in the
city and is used to city resources and methods. He assumes that there will be
the usual entrepreneurs, sophisticated materials and funds available in rural
areas, too.
To find an alternative to the private real estate system and a replacement for
reinforced concrete ‑ a target which is totally incompatible with the
mental attitude of many ‑ is a radical effort. The authorities in charge
of housing programs suffer from the desire to defend at all costs what they
would term the "proper" standard, usually interpreted as the
"nobility" of the materials rather than the comfort of the potential
occupants. Thus, they have to resort to whatever commercial system applies at
the time. This means plans drawn up by professionals in an architect’s office
and the use of a construction firm. The end result is that few houses are built
and those which are turn out expensive and ill‑adapted to the people
living in them.
Constructing
a whole new village is a unique opportunity, for it provides the framework in
which the physical environment of hundreds, sometimes thousands, of people will
be determined. Such a possibility of exercising choices does not often occur.
It can be used either to discover and implement new solutions for the
improvement of the new habitat of an entire village or, on the contrary, to
squander as yet another occasion for accumulating mistakes, for repeating
routine measures and for increasing inadequate solutions.
People
should be able to create a new physical environment and a new society in which,
to quote a phrase much beloved by Mozambican leaders, “all forms of
exploitation of man by man will come to an end”. Since what we have been discussing
are not ordinary villages but the nuclei of a new socialist society, one
fundamental question needs to be asked: Does the traditional farming community
represent a value to be developed or is it merely an amalgam of opposing forces
and interests, an illusion of democracy? Can it, or can it not, be used as a basis for creating new forms
of collective organisation?
In
the Soviet Union, the “agrarian revolution” went against the old mir peasant community. In China, the
village (albeit modified) was the linchpin of the new communes. Throughout the
Third World, especially in countries that base their development on socialist
principles, respect for traditional forms of settlement as a starting point for
a balanced development has been, and continues to be, a basic element even
though there have of course been nuances in the implementation and degrees of
acceptance and interpretation. Reactionaries tend to accentuate what is
picturesque, what is folklore, and coopt tribalism and native architectural
styles in order to highlight “typically local features”. A progressive
approach, on the other hand, consists of coopting a vast heritage of forms of
living (and spatial forms and technologies). Through study, development
alternatives are made in keeping with the new society to be constructed. This
is not a quick or linear process. The one certain thing is, however, that it
cannot be genuinely revolutionary unless it encompasses the real roots of the
people.